Attention, reputation and reciprocity behind the psychology of trust

Attention, reputation and reciprocity behind the psychology of trust

 

Cooperation with others, including strangers, has helped humanity prosper since throughout history. However, much of psychology of cooperation is still unexplained especially in the realm of indirect reciprocity, or cooperation without repeated encounters.

 

Dr Isamu Okada, Associate Professor at Soka University, is exploring the responses of people participating in reputation-based cooperation game to distinguish between the good who deserve to be cooperated with, and the bad.

 

Read more about Dr Okadas’ work in two papers from Scientific Reports, here and here.

 

 

Hello and welcome to Research Pod. Thank you for listening and joining us today. In this episode we will be looking at the research of Dr Isamu Okada from Soka University in Japan, who attempts to explain how human cooperation is characterised.

 

The ability to cooperate with others, including strangers, has generated prosperity within human society since the beginning of time. The evolution of cooperation has received much attention from social scientists, yet the concept of cooperation is still unexplained. When there is repetition, meaning that person A helps person B, and in turn B helps A, researchers call this direct reciprocity. But when there is no opportunity for repetition, the concept of indirect reciprocity offers a more substantial explanation. Indirect reciprocity means that cooperation is based on reputation rather than repetition. It is underpinned by social norms that enable us to distinguish between the good who deserve to be cooperated with, and the bad who should be refused cooperation. This can be observed with online services such as Amazon and eBay, where potential customers can check the vendors’ reputation and use this information to inform their decision of whether to make a purchase or not.

 

Indirect reciprocity involves assessment rules and draws on moral judgment. Studies have shown that these assessment rules achieve retributive justice, where donors cooperate with those who are good and do not cooperate with those who do not help the good. These rules are crucial to evolutionarily stabilise a cooperative regime. People acquire information through their assessment of others. With indirect reciprocity, the donor will decide whether or not to cooperate with the recipient based on the information that they have acquired regarding the recipient. The majority of studies so far assume that people will consider all of the information available to them. Dr Isamu Okada, Associate Professor at Soka University, Japan, is carrying out research that indicates that this assumption is implausible, and that people participating in indirect reciprocity exhibit selective inattention. This means that they actually ignore some of the information given to them.

 

So, how do people decide who to cooperate with?

 

Dr Okada explains that although people obtain a variety of information to assess others, the most important information relates to the previous actions of both donors and recipients. He refers to these as the ‘what data’ and ‘whom data’ respectively. Cooperative donors attract a good reputation while uncooperative or defective donors attract a bad reputation – this informs the what data. Since individuals can be both donors and recipients, theoretical analysis indicates that individuals who cooperate in their donor role but defect against those with poor reputations when in their recipient role will also foster a good reputation. Therefore, the evolutionary stability of cooperation involves the consideration of both whom data and what data. In other words, reputation information of both donors and recipients is required.

 

Previous empirical studies have shown that, when given the choice, people prefer to assess others using less complex information. But most theoretical studies into reputation-based cooperation assume that people base their assessments on all of the information available to them. Dr Okada’s research involves bridging the gap, integrating theory and empirical research. Results from his social psychology experiment reveal that while people willingly receive information, they do not automatically base their decisions on all of the information in their possession. This indicates that selective inattention occurs in reputation-based cooperation.

 

But how can we confirm whether or not selective inattention takes place?

 

Dr Okada recruited 152 university students to take part in his economic experiment. The participants play an online social dilemma game that involved making decisions on whether to cooperate with the recipient players. The research focus was on the behavioural differences associated with the information that was disclosed to the participants during the game. Participants took part in more than 50 rounds of the ‘indirect helping game’. In each round information was available on the actions of the recipient as well as the recipient’s recipients in the previous five rounds.

 

To date, the majority of reputation-based cooperation experiments have involved placing an order on the what data and whom data. Participants were able to acquire what data before acquiring whom data. That’s why what data is often referred to as first-order information and the whom data as second-order information. Dr Okada did not include this order constraint in his methodology and found that participants perceived what data and whom data independently. As a result of omitting the order constraint, he was able to observe cases where participants acquired the second-order information before the first-order information.

 

The experiment revealed that the participants’ decision-making varied, and that they made decisions based on the content of the information they received. When participants assumed the donor role and were informed that their recipients had previously interacted with players with bad reputations, the information did not have a significant influence on the participants’ decision-making. Moreover, when donor participants were given bad whom data, or second-order information regarding a recipient’s actions, the donors exhibited selective inattention behaviour in that they ignored both the whom data and the what data when making their decisions as to whether to cooperate or not. Where participants acquired the second-order information before the first-order information, and that second-order information was bad, they would not bother to acquire the first-order information.

 

Conversely, when the donor participants were informed that the recipients had previously interacted with players with good reputations and had good whom data, their decision-making was notably influenced by their recipients’ previous actions and the decisions depended on the what data.

 

It turns out that our decision making is dictated by social norms.

 

Dr Okada explains that selective inattention he observed in this study is consistent with a particular social norm of cooperation known as the Staying norm. The Staying norm dictates that if a recipient has a bad reputation, the observer ignores the donor’s behaviour and the donor’s reputation remains unchanged. In contrast, if the recipient’s reputation is good, if the donor cooperates the observer labels the donor as good. If the donor does not cooperate, the observer labels the donor as bad. This is followed by complex decision-making. Analysis of the Staying norm has shown it to be the most effective in establishing cooperation when compared with the established social norms.

 

Interestingly, cooperation with strangers reveals our moral values.

 

In addition to selective inattention, Dr Okada’s investigation has also revealed other properties of indirect reciprocity including justified defection, where participants declined to cooperate with bad recipients, as well as a prosocial chain, with participants promoting social acceptance. Dr Okada believes that these properties can be considered to be evolutionarily acquired traits. He writes: “Indirect reciprocity is a very social and complex cooperation mechanism that requires sophisticated cognitive systems and information processing. I believe that the properties we have identified have been an important adaptive basis for realising the complex cooperation mechanism.”

 

With this research Dr Okada has sought to resolve the conflicts between existing theory and empirical research. He has extracted indirect reciprocal norms that enable stable cooperation to be maintained and underpinned these with both his theoretical and empirical studies. Dr Okada explains that examining how we value others in order to foster cooperation with strangers essentially reveals our moral values and demonstrates what we consider to be good and bad. He concludes: “In my future work, I would like to clarify the reality of human moral judgment by empirical studies and confirm whether it can maintain stable cooperation from an evolutionary viewpoint by theoretical analysis.”

 

That’s all for this episode – thanks for listening, and stay subscribed to Research Pod for more of the latest science. See you again soon.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.

Top
Researchpod Let's Talk

Share This

Copy Link to Clipboard

Copy