Protest banner reading Climate justice now

Climate change economics: A net cost analysis of the Paris Agreement targets

 

Global temperature rises and climate change will not only bring disruption to the planet’s ecosystems, weather systems, and sea levels – they will also have an impact on current and future human societies through economic turmoil.

 

Dr Patrick Brown, of San José State University, finds out when the benefits of meeting the Paris Agreement targets will begin to outweigh the costs.

 

Read more in Research Outreach

 

Read more in these articles:

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0239520

https://doi.org/10.1038/s41586-018-0071-9

 

 

 

 

Hello and welcome to Research Pod. Thank you for listening and joining us today. In this episode we will be looking at the research of Dr Patrick Brown of San José State University. Dr Brown undertook a net cost analysis to find out when the benefits of meeting the Paris Agreement targets will begin to outweigh the costs.

 

Global temperature rises and climate change will not only bring disruption to the planet’s ecosystems, weather systems, and sea levels. It will also have an impact on current and future human societies through economic turmoil. One recent study by Marshall Burke and co-authors calculated the level of climate-related economic disruption to be far higher than previous estimates had suggested.

 

This new estimate of economic damage from climate change ostensibly vindicates the UN’s mitigation targets. It indicates that limiting global warming in 2100 to 1.5 C above preindustrial levels would save the world 36 trillion US-dollars in global total GDP compared to a 2.0 C rise, with a 3% discount rate, meaning how much a benefit declines in value each year.

 

If correct, the increased estimate of economic climate damage from Burke and co-authors will have enormous implications for the Paris Agreement. It highlights the clear economic benefits of limiting climate change and keeping warming to 1.5 C or 2.0 C, in line with the Paris Agreement. However, the Burke study does not factor in the high economic costs of limiting warming, for example through decarbonising the energy, transport, and industrial sectors. Therefore, to find the net cost of meeting the temperature targets, the Burke estimate must be weighed against mitigation costs.

 

For this reason, Dr Patrick Brown of San José State University analysed Burke’s amplified cost estimate against the cost of climate mitigation, to make a cost-benefit analysis. The study parameterised the new Burke data using the Dynamic Integrated Climate-Economy model, also referred to as the DICE model, setting Burke’s data against mainstream estimates of mitigation costs.

 

William Nordhaus was awarded the Nobel Prize for the conceptual framework that underlies the DICE model. DICE is an integrated assessment model for understanding the global economic implications of temperature targets such as the those in the Paris Agreement. It integrates economics, the carbon cycle, the impacts of global warming, and climate science to weigh the costs and benefits of mitigating climate change.

 

Dr Brown’s research takes the estimates from Burke et al. and weighs them against the DICE model’s representation of mitigation costs, which are tuned to be in line with the most-sophisticated mitigation cost estimates. He wanted to discover the net cost to global GDP over varying decarbonisation severities and across different time scales. The study fed the DICE model a spectrum of emissions reduction trajectories, which vary in their stringency and therefore cost. It looked over many temporal scales to ascertain when mitigation investments tip to become economically beneficial.

 

Dr Brown’s study focused on how global GDP will be affected by different intensities of mitigation and, consequently, levels of warming by 2100. With Burke’s heightened figures of climate damage incorporated into DICE, the year that mitigation efforts will become a net-economic positive shifts from the 22nd century to the late 21st century. However, Dr Brown’s study calculated that the costs of limiting global warming to 1.5 C and to 2 C are larger than the benefits through the year 2100.

 

The Burke study calculated that, without considering mitigation costs, stabilizing temperatures below 1.5 C would save the world roughly $36 trillion dollars in global GDP this century compared to limiting global warming to 2 C. But when Dr Brown’s study included mainstream cost estimates, this reversed the result of the calculation: they found that through the end of this century, limiting global warming to 1.5 C results in a net loss of global GDP of roughly $40 trillion relative to limiting global warming to 2 C. Even achieving the 2.0 C goal entailed a net loss of global GDP relative to no mitigation.

 

This indicates that if we were making a decision based only on global GDP and only on a time horizon of 2100, it would not be worth the expense to limit global warming to 1.5 C – or to 2.0 C for that matter. But achieving these targets would eventually pay off in the long run, which highlights that, economically at least, climate policies really may entail this generation sacrificing for future generations.

 

Another relevant factor in the equation was the discount rate of the mitigation effort. As this is a subjective metric, policymakers can change it when making evaluations. When the discount rate is above the 3% used by Burke, it does not justify as much climate change mitigation from a global GDP point of view. However, when the discount rate falls below 3%, more aggressive mitigation efforts become preferable. The inherent links between the discount rate and economic growth, coupled with the fact that economic growth is not exponential on a finite planet facing climate change, would point to discount rates being reduced over time, as the economic benefits of mitigation will increase over time.

 

The vast complexity of calculating the cost of global warming and mitigation measures has meant that this study’s results come with some caveats.

 

Firstly, the cost-benefit analysis was highly idealized and simplified, allowing for clearer inputs and answers. The estimates could be missing some essential features such as sea-level rise considered against sea-level rise adaptations. The study does not consider factors other than the economy, such as the subjective value of biodiversity. More holistically, they would take into consideration such things as climate migration etc.

 

These limitations and caveats notwithstanding, by using a modified DICE model Dr Brown’s study reveals that the time horizon on which the Paris Agreement might become economically beneficial is potentially near the end of this century.

 

Although the data reveals the clear economic benefits of more stringent mitigation efforts through 2300, limiting warming to 1.5 C and 2.0 C leads to a net loss over the remainder of this century. Thus, this study emphasizes the importance of considering the cost of mitigation when estimating the net cost of global temperature targets. It also highlights the importance of considering longer timelines and lower discount rates in these calculations.

 

Overall, the economic impact of climate change is one of the primary issues influencing scientific research, public opinion, and policy. This vital work from Dr Patrick Brown and San José State University highlights the asymmetry in the timing of the costs of mitigation against the benefits of avoided climate change, and therefore the long-term time frame under which mitigation investment pays off. The results of this study going forward will aid in developing and fine-tuning economic policy and will enable the assessment of future estimates of global warming costs through the modified DICE model used in this study.

 

That’s all for this episode – thanks for listening, and stay subscribed to Research Pod for more of the latest science. See you again soon.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.

Top
Researchpod Let's Talk

Share This

Copy Link to Clipboard

Copy